Showing posts with label Isoquant. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Isoquant. Show all posts

Law of Returns to Scale in Production | Increasing Returns to Scale | Constance Returns to Scale | Decreasing Returns to Scale

Returns to scale describe the change in output when all inputs are changed / increased by the same proportion. This means that returns to scale explains production activities over the long run. Over the long run, a firm can increase all inputs by equal proportion or by unequal proportion. Returns to scale is based on the assumption that over the long run all inputs of production are increased by equal proportion.

According to A. Koutsoyiannis, “The term returns to scale refers to the changes in output as all factors change by the same proportion.” This law of returns can also be defined as, “Returns to scale related to the behavior of total output as all inputs are varied and is a long run concept.”

When each of the inputs of production are increased proportionately, output may increases more than proportionately or less than proportionately or equi-proportionatly. If it increases more than the percentage increase in inputs, it is called increasing returns to scale (IRS); if output increases by less than the percentage increase in inputs it is called decreasing returns to scale (DRS); and if output increase by equal proportion to the increase in inputs, it is called constant returns to scale (CRS). The concept of returns to scale is summarized in table.

Table: Returns to Scale
Increase in the Quantity
 of Factors/inputs
Increase in OutputType of Returns
 to Scale
10%20%Increasing
10%10%Constant
10%5%Decreasing

Increasing returns to scale occur when the economies of scale operate. Diminishing returns to scale occur when the diseconomies of scale operate. Constant returns to scale are an intermediary situation, when certain advantages of large scale production are counterbalanced by certain disadvantages.

The law of returns of scale can be explained with the help of Isoquants for a single output with the use of two inputs.

i) Increasing Returns to Scale (IRS)


When a certain proportionate change in both the inputs K and L, leads to a more than proportionate change / increase in output, it exhibits increasing return to scale. For instance, if quantities of both the inputs, K and L are successively doubled and the corresponding output is more than doubled, the return to scale is to be increasing return. It is illustrated with the help of figure.

Increasing Returns to Scale

The movement from point A to B as the line / ray OR should mean doubling the inputs K and L. In above figure, input combination increases from 1K + 1L to 2K + 2L. As a result of doubling the inputs, output is more than doubled. Similarly, the movement from point A to B, B to C, C to D indicates increase in inputs as a result of which the output increases more than the increase in inputs. Along the ray OR, the gap between AB, BC and CD is decreasing, that is OA > AB > BC > CD.

Increasing returns to scale (IRS) means the reduction in average cost of production with the expansion in the scale of the firm and increase in the size of output. That is, increasing returns to scale is another name of decreasing average cost of production with increase in the size of production.

Causes of Increasing Returns to Scale


a) Specialization

Each worker can acquire specialization in the performance of simple repetitive task rather than many different tasks. As a result, labor productivity registers a rise.

b) Dimensional relation

Increasing returns to scale is a matter of dimensional relation. For example, when the size of cloths (10m x 20m = 200 sq. m) is doubled to 20m x 40m = 800 sq. m., the size of the cloth is more than doubled, 800 sq. m. is 4 times of 200 sq. m. Following this relationship, when labor and capital are doubled, output is more than doubled over initial level of output.

c) Use of specialized machinery

In addition, a large scale of operation permits the use of more productive specialized machinery, which was not possible at a smaller scale of operation.

d) Effect of research and development

Conduction of research and development (R & D) works modifies methods of production. Research and development bring efficiency, economy and effectiveness in the production process. Hence, more spending on research and development is possible only in firms of large size.

e) Use of indivisibilities

Capital equipment of a given capacity and entrepreneur skill are the indivisible factors. They cannot be sub-divided into parts. Hence, as output increases, there is better and effective utilization of these factors. Therefore, as a results of the effect of all these factors, a given proportionate increase in the amount of all inputs leads to more than proportionate increase in output.

ii) Constant Returns to Scale (CRS)


When the change in output is proportional to the change in inputs, it exhibits constant return to scale (CRS). In other words, if quantities of both inputs, K and L are doubled and output is also doubled, then returns to scale is said to be constant.

A production function showing constant returns to scale is often called ‘liner and homogenous’ or homogeneous of the first degree’. The case of CRS is illustrated by means of figure.

Constant Returns to Scale

In the figure, the movement from point A to B, B to C and C to D is assumed to indicate doubling of the inputs. When inputs are doubled, output is also doubled. Similarly, the movement from A to C indicates trebling input, output also trebling. The gap between AB, BC and CD is same, that is OA = AB = BC = CD which means that the distance of successive isoquants is equal in case of CRS.

The main reason for the operation of constant returns to scale is that beyond a certain point, internal and external economies are neutralized by the growing internal and external diseconomies of production. When inputs of same efficiency are duplicated, output would increase by equal proportion.

iii) Decreasing Returns to Scale (DRS)


When output increases in a smaller proportion than the increase in all inputs, decreasing returns to scale (DRS) are said to operate. When a firm goes on expanding by increasing all its inputs / resources of production, eventually decreasing returns to scale will occur. For example, when inputs are doubled and output will be less than doubled. The decreasing return to scale (IRS) is illustrated with the help of figure.

Decreasing Returns to Scale

When the inputs K and L are doubled, that is, when capital-labor combination is increased from 1K + 1L to 2K + 2L, output also increases but by less than the proportionate increase in inputs. The movement from A to B, B to C and C to D indicates increase in the inputs. But the output increases by less than the increase in inputs. The gap between AB, BC and CD is increasing, that is AB < BC < CD. When decreasing returns to scales applies, the distance of successive isoquants along the ray through origin increases. Decreasing returns to scale also means increase in average cost of production with the expansion in the size and output of the firm.

Causes of Decreasing Returns to Scale


i) Managerial inefficiency

With the fast expansion of the scale of production, personal contacts and communication between (a) owners and management and (b) managers and labor, get rapidly reduced. Remote control and management replace close control and supervision. With the increase in managerial personnel / staff, decision-making becomes complex and delay in decision-making becomes inevitable. Implementation of decision is also delayed due to co-ordination problem between different sections and/or branches. As a result, output increases less than proportionately than the proportionate increase in inputs.

ii) Labor inefficiency

Another cause of decreasing returns to scale is over crowding of labor causing to loss of labor productivity and their accountability. On the other hand, increase in number of workers encourages labor union activities which mean simply the loss of output per unit of time.

iii) Exhaustible natural resources

The decreasing returns to scale may be found in the use of exhaustible natural resources. For example, if more and more fisherman used to fishing in a certain area of Trishuli river of Nepal, the catching of the fish will not increase in the same proportion.

iv) Fiscal diseconomies

With the expansion of the scale of production, the discount and concession that are available on bulk purchase of inputs come to end. As a result, output increases less proportion than the proportionate increase in all output.

  You may also like to read:                   

Production of maximum output in the firm | Production of a given output at minimum cost | Production of maximum output with a given level of cost

Production of maximum output in the firm is possible in the given level of expenditure which can be studied with the help of Iso-cost curve and Iso-quant curve.

It is clear that any desired level of output can be produced by a number of different combinations of inputs. But the manager of the firm most make major decisions such as which input combination to be used, what the input, combination will be optimal.

The firm can choose from among different combinations of capital (K) and Labor (L) to produce a given level of output or faced with specified input prices, it can choose from among many combinations of K and L that would lead to fixed level of cost i.e. expenditure. Thus, the firm has to make either of two input choice decision.
  1. Choose the input combination that yields the maximum level of output possible with a fixed output (i.e. output maximization subject to cost constraint).
  2. Choose the input combination that leads to the lowest cost of producing a fixed level of output (i.e. cost minimization subject to output constraint).

The solution to any constrained maximization or minimization problem is obtained by choosing the level of each activity whereby the marginal benefits from each activity. Per dollar ($) spend are equal. Here the profit maximizing firm has to choose the input combination for which the marginal product divided by input price is the same for all inputs used. The implication is that for two input cases, a firm attains the highest level of output when,

MP/ PL = MP/ PK or MPw = MPr

Where, w and r are respectively the prices of labor (PL) and capital (PK). Thus, the MRTS = MP/ MPK equals the factor price ratio (wr).

Input Prices and Iso-costs


The Iso-quant shows the desire of the producer. Usually, a firm is supposed to have a fixed amount of money to buy resources. The Iso-cost line is the producer’s budget line. In determining the optimal input combination, a profit maximizing producing unit firm or producer has to pay attention to relative input prices, it is to minimize the cost of producing a given output or maximizing output for a given level of cost. Input prices are determined by the market forces.

The equation of total cost is C = rK + wL where all the terms have their usual meaning. Total cost is simply the sum of the cost of K units of capital at r $ per unit of L units of labor at w $ per units.

Suppose, capital costs $100 per month per unit (r = $100) and labor receives a wage of $200 per unit (w = S200). Then the firm’s total cost function is

C = 100 K + 200 L ……………………. (i)

Now, suppose that the firm decides to spend $2000 per month for capital and labor. Thus, equation becomes $2000 = $100 K + 200 L.

The process of solving this equation is

     2000 = 100 K + 200 L
or, K = 200 – 2 L

In a general situation, if a fixed amount Ḹ is to be spent, the firm can choose among the combinations given by

K = Ḹ/r – w/r . L

Production of a given Output at Minimum Cost


Whatever output a firm chooses to produce, the production manager is desirous of producing it at the lowest possible cost. To achieve this objective, the production process must not only to be technically efficient but economically efficient too. So, the production process has to organize in the most efficient manner.

For example, suppose that at given input prices r and w, a firm wishes to produce the output indicated by Iso-quant Q0 as shown in the figure.


In the figure, KL1, KL2 and KL3 are the three Iso-cost lines from which the producer can choose at the given factor prices. The firm will choose the lowest level of expenditure that enables output level Q0 = 200 to be produced. As shown in the figure, output level Q0 will be produced at the cost level Q0 will be produced at the cost represented by Iso-cost line KL1.

Any cost outlay below that such as represented by KL is not feasible since it is impossible to produce output Q0 with these factor combinations. Any factor combinations above that represented by K1L1 are not considered because the firm seeks to produce the desired output at least cost. If combination A or B is chosen at the cost outlay represented by K2L2, the producer can reduce costs by moving along Q0 to point E. Point E shows the optimal resource combination, K0 units of capital and L0 units of labor. This is known as the level of cost combination of inputs.

This Iso-quant shows the desired rate of factor substitution and the Iso-cost is the actual rate of factor substitution. A firm reaches equilibrium and thus minimizes cost when the Iso-quant is tangent to the lowest possible Iso-cost line. Thus, equilibrium is reached when the Iso-quant representing the chosen output is just tangent to an Iso-cost line. At this tangent the slopes of the two curves are equal, production at least cost requires that the MRTS (Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution) of capital for labor be equal to the ratio of the price of labor to the price of capital.

      MPL PMK = w / r

or, MPL / w = MPK / r

where, MPL = Marginal production of labor
MPK = Marginal productivity of capital
        r = Price of capital
       w = Price of labor

Production of Maximum Output with a given Level of Cost


It is an alternative technique but more preferable way of presenting the optimization problem. It is to assume that the firm chooses a level of output and then select the factor combination that permits production of that output at least cost. This approach seems to be more practical than the previous one. It is assumed that the firm can spend only a fixed amount of money to spend and it seeks to attain the highest level of output consistent with that amount of outlay. It can be explained with the help of figure below:


The Iso-cost line KL shows all possible combination of the two inputs that can be purchased with a fixed market prices. Three Iso-quants are shown in the figure. At the given level of cost, output level Q2 is unattainable. Neither output level Q1 nor level Q2 would be chosen, since higher levels of output can be produced with the fixed cost outlay. The highest possible output with the given level of cost is produced by using OL0 amount of labor and OK0 amount of capital. At point E, the highest attainable Iso-quant (i.e. Q) is just tangent to the given Iso-cost (KL). Thus, in the case of constrained output maximization, the MRTS of capital for labor equal the input-price ratio (the price of labor to the price of capital).

 You may also like to read: